Engaged Egalitarianism: Why the Australian Recovery Must Prioritise Openness - Speech, Melbourne

ENGAGED EGALITARIANISM: WHY THE AUSTRALIAN RECOVERY MUST PRIORITISE OPENNESS

Stan Kelly Lecture
Economic Society of Victoria, Melbourne

Whenever I take one of my sons to an outdoors shop, I like to point out the Clif Bars. ‘Do you remember how they got their name?’, I’ll ask them. Wearily – because we’ve done this routine a dozen times – they’ll roll their eyes. ‘Yes, dad’, he’ll reply. ‘Gary Erickson had the idea for a great product and named it after his dad’. ‘That’s right, son!’, I’ll reply. ‘And don’t you think there’s a lesson for all of us in that?’.

Like Gary Erickson, Bert Kelly honoured his father in creating today’s talk – truly the act of a ‘modest member’. Stan Kelly was a campaigner for free trade in an era when it was deeply unpopular. When Australian industry was settling down for a long snooze behind high tariff walls, he was arguing for the benefits of trade liberalisation. In 1929, Stan Kelly joined the Tariff Board. The next year, President Hoover signed the Smoot-Hawley Act into law, raising tariffs on over 20,000 goods. This was not a propitious time to be a free trader.

To be a Victorian free trader was tougher still. At the time of Federation, the colony of New South Wales was the only strong voice for free trade. Premier George Reid famously said that for New South Wales to join the federation was akin to a reformed alcoholic setting up house with five drunkards, leaving the question of beverages to be decided later by majority vote. Yet over the coming decades, Victoria did produce the occasional free trader. Stan Kelly was one. Bert Kelly was another.

Bert was a proud Liberal Party representative. I’m a Labor true believer. I’ve never shared Bert Kelly’s electoral politics, but have always admired his ability to argue for sound economic policy with a well-chosen anecdote and a witty turn of phrase. The book of his modest member columns – Economics Made Easy – sits next to my desk in my Parliament House office. It’s fun to thumb through. In one 1979 column, Bert Kelly says that almost all economists are unpopular, and if they aren’t, that is because they are ‘not good economists or they are deceiving people’. Bracing words for any economist who wishes to win re-election.

It is an honour to follow in the footsteps of those who have given this lecture before me, including Anne Krueger, Ross Garnaut, Leslie Melville, John Stone and Bob Hawke. My thanks to the remarkably pansophic Alex Millmow and the Economic Society of Victoria for inviting me.

Openness and Average Living Standards

Even prior to COVID, there were signs that globalisation was in trouble. World trade volumes, which had outstripped world output for decades, began to slow (Leigh 2017). The election of populists in many countries threatened international institutions. Britain withdrew from the European Union, and American intransigence damaged the World Trade Organisation’s ability to resolve trade disputes.

The COVID pandemic accentuated that slide, just as the 1918-20 influenza pandemic helped to derail globalisation a century earlier (see eg Siklos 2021). Pandemics increase our fear of foreigners and lend power to the isolationists. COVID empowered those who believe in shutting out the world, and made life tougher for those who believe in the benefits of engaged multilateralism and diverse multiculturalism. COVID empowered racists, xenophobes, protectionists, chauvinists and jingoists.

But to adapt Monty Python, what has economic openness ever done for us anyway? One way to answer this question is to look at whether there is any relationship between Australian living standards and economic openness. As a measure of relative living standards, I create a new metric: the share of the world’s population who live in countries with higher average living standards than Australia, based on population and GDP data from the Maddison Project Database (Bolt and Luiten van Zanden 2020).

This effectively looks at our performance in the living standards Olympics, weighting countries by their population size. To be beaten by Luxembourg matters less than if we are poorer, on average, than the United States. Although this measure has the disadvantage that it does not take account of the distribution of incomes within countries, it has the significant advantage that we can estimate it over nearly two centuries. When plotting it, I reverse the scale, to reflect the fact that better economic performance means being beaten by a smaller share of the world.

As a measure of openness, I use the sum of imports and exports divided by twice the national output. Both incoming and outgoing trade flows matter for openness, but simply summing them together and dividing them by GDP risks producing a figure that exceeds 100 percent (since GDP does not include imports). Dividing by twice GDP averts this problem. These data are drawn from Butlin, Dixon and Lloyd (2015) and Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade (2020).

Figure 1 shows these two metrics. During the 1850s and 1860s, Australian living standards were so high than only 2-5 percent of the world’s population dwelt in more affluent countries. From 1875 to 1891 (with the sole exception of 1882), Australia had the highest per-capita incomes in the world. By the early-1900s, Australia’s relative standing had begun to fall, and in the 1930s, almost 10 percent of the world’s population lived in countries richer than Australia. During the post-war decades, we climbed up the ranking a bit, with around 7 percent of the world’s population outperforming us. Then from the early-1990s we rose further still. Since the late-1990s, Australia has been in the top 5 percent of living standards globally.

What about openness? During the mid-1800s, our openness share was around one-third, though this figure fell to about 15 percent by the 1880s. Openness fell in the 1930s and during World War II, rose immediately after the war ended, and then dropped again during the 1950s and 1960s. It steadily increased through the 1980s and 1990s, and has remained at around 16 percent during the 2000s.

The two series are clearly not perfectly correlated. For example, when Australia had the highest average living standards in the world, its level of economic openness was declining (albeit off a high base). Yet the two series do move together in the period after the second World War, and during the 1980s and 1990s. Indeed, this association is statistically significant association. The simple pairwise correlation between the living standards measure and the openness measure is significant at the 1 percent level (although this does not account for serial correlation). On its face, this implies that at times when Australia has been more open to the world, we have enjoyed higher living standards.

Yet averages only take us so far. When Elon Musk walks into a bar, the average wealth per person is over a billion dollars. But that doesn’t mean that every drinker is a billionaire. Since at least the formulation of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem, economists have recognised that economic openness can benefit some while hurting others.

It is therefore helpful to look at the specific impacts of imports, immigration and foreign investment on Australian living standards.

Imports and Inequality

A standard result from the distributional analysis of consumption taxes is that they operate in a regressive manner. Because high-income households have higher savings rates than low-income households, expenditure taxes impose a larger burden on the poor. To take a simple example, suppose that an affluent household has a saving rate of 20 percent, while a disadvantaged household does not save at all. A broad-based consumption tax of 10 percent would equate to a 10 percent tax on the total income of the poor household, but only 8 percent on the total income of the rich household.

Because tariffs are consumption taxes on imports, tariffs on most products are regressive (in the sense that they constitute a higher share of income for low-income households than for high-income households). Table 1 shows expenditure as a share of gross income across household income quintiles, as estimated from the 2016-17 Household Expenditure Survey (the most recent available), for a number of expenditure categories that are subject to tariffs.

Food shows an especially steep gradient, with the lowest-income households spending 26 percent of income on food and beverages, compared with just 9 percent for the highest-income households. For the categories of clothing and footwear, and household furnishings and equipment, expenditure takes up twice the share of a poor household’s income as it does for a rich household’s income. In the case of motor vehicles, the pattern is less pronounced, but vehicle purchase is still a larger share of income for low-income households than it is for high-income households. Books and other printed materials comprise the smallest budget share in the table, but the gradient is as steep as for food and beverages, with the budget share on books being three times as large for poor households as for rich households.

Table 1: Expenditure on Selected Items as a Share of Gross Income, by Income Quintile

 

Lowest

Second

Third

Fourth

Highest

Food and beverages

25.82%

18.54%

15.54%

12.74%

8.54%

Clothing and footwear

3.23%

2.56%

2.35%

2.24%

1.61%

Household furnishings and equipment

4.94%

3.59%

2.97%

2.52%

2.33%

Motor vehicles

2.82%

2.31%

2.67%

2.60%

2.34%

Books and other printed material

0.67%

0.46%

0.42%

0.29%

0.18%

Source: Author’s calculations, based on the 2016-17 Household Expenditure Survey

Precise tariff levels are difficult to calculate for these various expenditure categories. Tariffs vary by country, with free trade agreements often reducing the basic tariff levels. Product categories of tariffs do not correspond directly to categories of household expenditure, sometimes because products are imported as raw materials, and then assembled into finished products. Assumptions must also be made about the degree to which retailers mark up tariffs that are applied at the importation stage.

However, these complications are unlikely to affect the distributional impact of tariffs. For example a clothing tariff that raised retail prices by 5 percent would equate to a 0.16 percent tax on the incomes of the poorest households, but a 0.08 percent tax on the incomes of the richest households. Similarly, a motor vehicle tariff that raised retail prices by 5 percent would equate to a 0.14 percent tax on the incomes of the poorest households, but a 0.12 percent tax on the incomes of the richest households. The basic point is simple: virtually all tariffs are regressive.

This straightforward result suggests that past reductions in tariffs have had a progressive impact. According to a study by the Centre for International Economics (2017), trade liberalisation between 1986 and 2016 increased real incomes by $8,448 for the typical household. In proportionate terms, this is likely to have a greater impact on poor households than on rich households. Appropriately, trade liberalisation during the 1980s was accompanied by structural adjustment plans for workers in the textile, clothing and footwear sectors – recognising that despite the aggregate community benefit of lower prices, there was also an employment cost in those industries.

In some cases, the price impacts have been remarkable. Attending school in the 1970s and 1980s, I recall school shoes being a significant impost on my middle-class parents. That need not be true today. In Leigh (2017), I looked back through old newspapers to gauge the impact of trade liberalisation on Australian prices. In 1987, Kmart sold children’s shoes for $10 and men’s work boots for $28. Thirty years later, in 2017, Kmart sold children’s shoes for $9 and men’s work boots for $34. In other words, Kmart could have kept the same prices on their shoe shelves for thirty years, from the age of Dirty Dancing to the era of Ed Sheeran. The shelf tags would be scuffed and yellowed, but the prices would have remained accurate to within a few dollars, despite a tripling in nominal wages over that interval.

Lower tariffs didn’t just mean cheaper products; it meant more choices. As tariffs fell, it became viable for retailers to import a vast range of products that simply weren’t economic to sell in the high-tariff era. Over the past generation, the number of different car models sold in Australia has tripled. Our supermarkets stock more product lines than ever before. If you have a quirky hobby, play an unusual sport, or enjoy a rare cuisine, then you’re likely to have benefited from trade liberalisation. Indeed, one study suggests that the consumer benefit of a wide range of goods might be larger than the consumer benefit of cheaper prices.

The foundation of trade is the principle of comparative advantage. If you pay someone else to cut your hair and fix your car, then you already enjoy the benefits of comparative advantage locally. International trade just represents the same idea on a global scale. Shadow Trade Minister Madeleine King has pointed out that if every nation had to supply all its own medical equipment, ‘healthcare costs would soar’ (King 2020). Try treating your ailments only with medications that were invented and produced in Australia, and you’ll quickly see how the global flow of innovation and products has made us healthier.

Economist James Ingram (1970) once pointed out that we can think of trade as akin to a magical machine that turns our exports into imports. We fill ships with iron ore, wheat and gold. They return laden with furniture, trucks and smartphones. The magical ‘trade machine’ produces these things more cheaply than would be possible than if we had to build them domestically. That’s comparative advantage in action.

Yet over recent years, the number of harmful trade measures has risen sharply. For over a decade, Global Trade Alert, an initiative of the London-based Centre for Economic Policy Research, has tracked the number of harmful trade restrictions. From 2009 to 2021, this figure by one-quarter, from 2,098 to 2,684. Across this period, Australia was the victim of 1.1 percent of harmful trade restrictions, and perpetrator of 1.4 percent of harmful trade restrictions. Global Trade Alert estimates that in 2009, 28 percent of Australian exports were at risk from harmful trade measures. By 2021, this figure had risen to 73 percent (Evenett and Fritz 2021, 80).

What holds true for trade in general also holds true for trade with China. As the Australian National University’s Shiro Armstrong (2020) notes, ‘free trade that excludes China is not free trade’, since more supply chains run through China than any other nation. Because of this, China has a huge stake in maintaining a rules-based international trading order, and Australia has a strong interest in encouraging the Chinese leadership to maintain the system that has massively benefited their nation since China joined the World Trade Organisation in 2001.

Rather than lambasting ‘negative globalism’, engaged egalitarianism demands that Australia plays a more active role in campaigning globally for trade liberalisation. Within APEC, we could press for agreements that countries will not impose additional trade restrictions on food and essential medical supplies. In the World Trade Organisation, Australia ought to be encouraging a comprehensive, long-term solution to the breakdown of the dispute resolution process (a particular disappointment is the fact that the Biden Administration’s approach to the WTO does not differ markedly from that of the Trump Administration). Regionally, Australia should encourage the conclusion of the 15-member Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership, which covers the ten ASEAN states, plus Australia, China, Japan, New Zealand, and South Korea.

Naturally, trade agreements can also boost Australian exports, on which I have said very little. This is not because exports are unimportant, but because they tend to dominate the thinking of trade policymakers, and because their impact on living standards is so clear cut. Exports expand the pool of customers to whom businesses can sell their goods and services. This allows firms to expand and create more jobs. Across the economy, 14 percent of the workforce are employed in export-related activities (Centre for International Economics 2017, 9). If its production technology exhibits increasing returns to scale, exports can also increase productivity and wages. Empirical evidence supports this: exporters have labour productivity growth that is 2 percent higher, and pay wages that are nearly 3 percent higher (Tuhin and Swanepoel 2017). Because the evidence on the positive effects of exporting is so strong, I will not devote more time to analysing its effects, and will turn now to the issue of immigration and inequality.

Immigration and Inequality

When it comes to migrants, it’s too easy to forget that those who come to Australia bring not just a mouth to feed, but two hands to work and a mind to inspire. Immigrants are overrepresented among start-up entrepreneurs and leading researchers. When I worked in a highly productive research department at the Australian National University, most of my economist colleagues were foreign born, and some were on temporary visas. With one-quarter of Australians born overseas, immigration has been a major driver of productivity growth. One-third of Australia’s Nobel laureates – including Brian Schmidt, J.M. Coetzee, Patrick White, and Bernard Katz – were immigrants.

The greatest beneficiaries of migration are the migrants themselves. Using visa lottery programs as a randomised evaluation, a study of Indians who migrated to the United States found that they increased their earnings sixfold. Facilitating orderly migration is one of the best ways of reducing global poverty levels, particularly if it is accompanied by measures to reduce the costs of sending remittances back. Globally, remittances exceed the total value of all foreign aid. Remittances account for 41 percent of GDP in Tonga, 29 percent in Nepal, and 18 percent in Samoa. For these nations, migrants matter.

The impact of immigration on wages has been hotly debated by economists. A 2016 literature review conducted by the OECD identified twenty-eight studies on immigration and wages (OECD 2016). Of these, thirteen reported no effect, seven a small positive effect, and eight a small negative effect. The review identified a similar pattern with respect to the impact of immigration and employment, with most of the research failing to back up the claim that ‘migrants rob jobs’. The leading Australian study (Breunig, Deutscher and To 2017) reached the same conclusion. To the extent that economists have found evidence of local workers being hurt by migration, it seems to occur when the existing workers have similar skills to the new arrivals and when the influx is very large.

To the extent that migrants affect wages and employment, it is crucial to ask ‘whose wages?’. For example, a country dominated by low-skill immigration might experience a large influx of gardening hands. If the inflow is large enough, they might decrease wages among native-born gardening hands. In principle, this could reduce the welfare of low-wage gardening hands, and benefit those households that are rich enough to afford a gardener. Anecdotally, it appears much more common for affluent households in San Diego to pay someone else to mow their lawns than it does for households in a similar position in the income distribution in Sydney.

Conversely, a country that facilitates migration by medical doctors might find that it reduces the rate of wage growth among native-born doctors. This in turn may flow through to the prices and availability of medical services for those who use them most. In Australia’s case, 56 percent of GPs and 47 percent of specialists are overseas-born (ABS 2013). Since low-income households make more GP visits and are more likely to have a chronic illness (Elkins and Schurer 2017), the beneficiaries of these immigration settings are disproportionately found in lower-income households.

What do we know about the earnings of Australian migrants? In Figure 2, I use data from the 2016 Census (the most recent Census from which data are available) to calculate the personal income distribution of skilled permanent migrants. This is compared with the distribution of personal income among the Australian-born population. The chart shows that skilled permanent migrants are overrepresented among those with zero or negative incomes, suggesting that some may struggle to find work. However, conditional on being in the labour force, skilled permanent migrants tend to earn more than the Australian-born population. Skilled permanent migrants are less likely to earn annual incomes between $1 and $41,599, but more likely to earn incomes above $41,600. The gap is particularly noteworthy in the higher categories, with skilled permanent migrants being much likely to earn between $104,000 and $155,999 (9 percent compared with 6 percent), and substantially more likely to earn $156,000 or more (5 percent compared with 3 percent).

Although there is scope to refine the operation of Australia’s migration program (see eg Coates, Sherrell and Mackey 2021, 2022), this result suggests that the permanent skilled migration program is unlikely to increase income inequality. To the extent that immigrants through this program have an impact on the wages of Australian-born workers (and we know from the literature that such effects are likely to be small), this is likely to have an equalising effect on the income distribution.

Naturally, this result may differ across migration categories. A similar analysis of the income distribution of temporary visa holders, or permanent visa holders who have come through the family or humanitarian intakes, is likely to show an income distribution that is closer to the Australian-born population, or perhaps even lower. However, those programs are not mainly focused on economic outcomes. In the case of programs that are aimed to unite families or provide safety to asylum seekers, it is not reasonable to expect migrants’ incomes to exceed those in the general population.

As a share of our population, few countries have successfully welcomed as many migrants as Australia. This makes us ideally suited to help lead a global conversation on managing migrant inflows. As Columbia University’s Jeffrey Sachs (2016) points out, ‘There is no international regime that establishes standards and principles for national migration policies, other than in the case of refugees.’ This should be a priority for engaged egalitarians.

Investment and Inequality

In recent years, one dollar in nine of domestic investment in Australia has come from overseas (Leigh 2017). Australia’s reliance on overseas capital dates to the earliest days of European settlement. Throughout Australia’s history, investment from Britain, the United States, Japan and China has helped fuel economic growth. Foreign investors don’t just bring cash, they also contribute know-how. British pharmaceutical firm AstraZeneca has been operating in Australia since 1957, carrying out research and development with local medical researchers, and currently employing around 900 people. In 2017, they upgraded their North Ryde manufacturing plant with a $100 million investment in smart manufacturing. Each year, they carry out half a dozen clinical trials in Australia. Foreign investment can also provide competitive pressure. For example, Aldi’s entry into the supermarket industry caused Coles and Woolworths to lower their prices (Productivity Commission 2020).

Often, the choice isn’t foreign or local, it’s foreign or nothing. When Japanese company Toyota and American firm General Motors ceased building cars in Australia in 2017, no local investors stepped in. Instead, the factories shuttered, and thousands of workers lost their jobs. When the owners of Cubbie Station went into voluntary administration in 2009, no local buyers volunteered to purchase the 93,000 hectare cotton property. Had investors from Japan and China not bought the property in 2013, it might not have remained a viable operation. As the late NSW Premier Neville Wran once quipped about foreign investment in agricultural land: ‘they can’t take it with them’.

Investing in Australia provides a welcome source of diversification for overseas pension funds. To mitigate risk for their members, Canadian retirement funds such as the Ontario Teachers’ Pension Plan have invested in Australian piggeries, dairy farms and feedlots. At the same time, Australia’s superannuation funds are increasingly investing overseas, helping ensure that retirees don’t have all their nest eggs in a single basket. The idea here is akin to the reason why workers shouldn’t have all their retirement savings in the company they work for: if the firm goes bust, you lose your job and your investments. But if you have investments in other firms, you diversify your risk. Likewise, investing some of your superannuation overseas helps buffer the risk of a significant slump in the Australian economy.

Foreign investment can also help reduce trade conflict, by giving foreigners a stake in the success of the Australian economy. Triggs (2020) points to the example of Indonesia, which for years restricted beef exports from Australia. But as Indonesian firms invested in the Australian cattle industry, Indonesia’s incentive to curtail our beef exports has been substantially reduced.

A common myth is that Australia makes it especially easy for foreign investors. In fact, Australia’s foreign investment screening is already more stringent than in most advanced nations. The OECD’s foreign direct investment regulatory restrictiveness index measures openness on a scale of 0 (completely open) to 1 (completely closed). Its latest analysis, based on 2020 data for 30 OECD member nations, ranked Australia the 5th-most restrictive nation, with a score of 0.149, significantly more restrictive than the OECD average of 0.07 (Figure 3).

The many advanced countries that are more welcoming to foreign investment than Australia include Britain, Japan, Germany and the United States. Looking in the opposite direction, one of the few nations that has tougher foreign investment screening rules than Australia is New Zealand. According to a recent Productivity Commission study, if Australia tightened our foreign investment rules to match those across the Tasman, net investment would decline by 1.3 percent, Gross Domestic Product would fall by 0.26 percent, and Gross National Income would fall by 0.17 percent (Productivity Commission 2020, 103).

In recent decades, ‘capital deepening’ has been a major source of productivity gains. Simply put, investing in better industrial machines, newer computers, and more efficient offices increases the amount that each worker can produce each hour. In the long-run, productivity gains are the main source of wage growth. So if we want fatter pay packets, foreign investment can help. Scarce factors earn higher returns, so banning foreign investment would raise the rate of return for existing capital owners. Since capital is highly concentrated, this would deliver windfall gains to the most affluent.

Specifically, the Productivity Commission analysis estimates that tightening Australian foreign investment rules to match New Zealand’s would lead to a 0.25 percent increase in the rate of return on capital, and a 0.24 percent fall in wages. For a worker on median earnings ($1200 per week), this would equate to a $150 annual loss. Part of this wage loss is driven by job loss, with some sectors likely to shed jobs if foreign capital dries up. Although foreign investment tends to be concentrated in sectors with above-average earnings (such as mining, manufacturing and financial services), the combination of a wage reduction and an increase in the return on domestic capital would probably increase overall income inequality. At the very least, we know from the GNI and GDP results that it would reduce aggregate economic wellbeing.

Engaged egalitarianism recognises that foreign investment can boost equality. One way to think about foreign investment is that it raises the ratio of capital to labour in an economy. If labour markets work as they should, then more capital per worker ought to lead to higher wages. Just as workers earn less in capital-scarce Uganda than capital-rich Switzerland, so too Australian workers should benefit from an increase in the national capital stock. That’s true whether the investor lives in Townsville, Toronto or Tokyo.

Conclusion

Over the past two centuries, Australia’s economic performance on the global stage has been strongest when the nation is most engaged with the world. In the 1880s, when Australia’s income per-person placed us number one in the world, the trade share was high (Figure 1). That was also a period in which foreign investment funded almost half of all domestic investment (Kirchner 2020). And many Australians were new immigrants. Indeed, of all the migrants who left Europe between 1851 and 1915, 7 percent went to Australia, making us the third most popular destination – a remarkable statistic for a country so small and so distant (McLean 2013, 106). The earnings gap in that era was vast. Nineteenth century labourers in Sydney earned twice as much as their counterparts in San Francisco and Chicago.

By contrast, Australia’s retreat into isolationism, behind the walls of White Australia and tariffs, saw the country slip backwards in relative terms from other countries’ living standards and productivity. When the economy re-globalised in the 1980s and 1990s, we began climbing the ladder – closing the gap in living standards between us and more internationally engaged nations.

But Australia still has a productivity problem, and our lack of global engagement is part of the challenge. Kirchner (2020) reports that Australia’s trade share is substantially lower than typical high-income country. On the 2021 KOF Globalisation Index (Gygli et al 2019), Australia ranks 28th, nestled between Croatia and Malaysia. Australia could also benefit from increasing the diversity of our economy. On the Harvard Atlas of Economic Complexity, Australia ranks 86th, putting us just between Oman and Uzbekistan. We’re not just too disengaged from the world; we also have too many economic eggs in too few baskets.

Autarky is not only bad for productivity, it can also worsen inequality. Tariffs on imports tend to be regressive, so increasing trade restrictions imposes a larger burden on poor households. Skilled permanent migration to Australia has seen an influx of high-wage earners, so even if migration reduces wages (for which the evidence is patchy), the impact of skilled migration may be to reduce earnings inequality. Modelling of foreign investment suggests that a more restrictive approach would reduce wages. The same is doubtless true of a reduction in exports, which would effectively amount to shrinking the market size for Australian firms.

In the spirit of Stan and Bert Kelly, I have outlined a few ideas about how Australia could step up our global approach, guided by the philosophy of engaged egalitarianism. On the trade front, we should work to reduce harmful trade measures and improve the World Trade Organisation’s dispute settlement process. On immigration, we should work with other nations to develop a more unified approach to people flows. On foreign investment, we should avoid tightening screening. There are also other opportunities for leadership – including in the OECD, the G20 and even the G7 – which could provide a chance for Australia to pursue an engaged egalitarian agenda.

If Australia is to build back better after COVID, it is vital that we remember the many ways in which globalisation has shaped our nation for the better. With 0.3 percent of the world’s population, Australia stands to benefit from being connected to the world, through trade, migration and investment. If our nation rejects the benefits of openness – either through xenophobia or a broader failure to step up to regional leadership – then we may end up poorer and more unequal. Conversely, an engaged egalitarian approach reflects Australia’s values and our history, and offers a bright future for our nation and the globe.

ENDS

Authorised by Paul Erickson, ALP, Canberra.

References

Armstrong, Shiro. 2020. ‘Economic distancing from China and the world would carry heavy costs’, East Asia Forum, 7 June

Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2013, Australian Social Trends, April 2013, Cat No. 4102.0, ABS, Canberra.

Bolt, Jutta and Jan Luiten van Zanden (2020), ‘Maddison style estimates of the evolution of the world economy. A new 2020 update’, available at https://www.rug.nl/ggdc/historicaldevelopment/maddison/?lang=en

Breunig, Robert, Nathan Deutscher and Hang Thi To, 2017, ‘The Relationship between Immigration to Australia and the Labour Market Outcomes of Australian Workers’, Economic Record 93, Issue 301, pp.255–276.

Butlin, M., R. Dixon and P.J. Lloyd. 2015. ‘Statistical Appendix: selected data series, 1800–2010’ in S. Ville and G. Withers (eds), The Cambridge Economic History of Australia, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp.555-594

Centre for International Economics. 2017. ‘Australian trade liberalisation: Analysis of the economic impacts’, Report Prepared for the Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade, CIE, Canberra.

Coates, Brendan, Sherrell, Henry and Mackey, Will. 2021. Rethinking permanent skilled migration after the pandemic, Grattan Institute, Melbourne.

Coates, Brendan, Sherrell, Henry and Mackey, Will. 2022. Fixing temporary skilled migration: a better deal for Australia, Grattan Institute, Melbourne.

Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade, 2020, ‘Country and commodity pivot table 2006 to 2019’. Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade, Canberra.

Elkins, Rosemary and Schurer, Stefanie, (2017),  Introducing a GP Copayment in Australia: Who Would Carry the Cost Burden?,  Austaxpolicy: Tax and Transfer Policy Blog,  14 March 2017.

Evenett, Simon and Johannes Fritz, 2021, Subsidies and Market Access Towards an Inventory of Corporate Subsidies by China, the European Union and the United States: The 28th Global Trade Alert Report, CEPR Press, London.

Gygli, Savina, Florian Haelg, Niklas Potrafke and Jan-​Egbert Sturm (2019): The KOF Globalisation Index – Revisited, Review of International Organizations, 14(3), 543-​574

Ingram, James. 1970. International Economic Problems, John Wiley, New York.

King, Madeleine. 2020. ‘Why free trade can save us’, Australian Financial Review, 27 April.

Kirchner, Stephen. 2020. ‘Failure to converge? The Australia-US productivity gap in long-run perspective’. United States Studies Centre, University of Sydney, Sydney.

Leigh, Andrew. 2017. Choosing Openness: Why Global Engagement is Best for Australia, Penguin, Sydney.

Leigh, Andrew. 2020. ‘Engaged Egalitarianism: Reinvigorating Globalisation in the Post COVID Age’, Australian Fabians Review, Issue 1.

McLean, Ian, 2013, Why Australia Prospered: The Shifting Sources of Economic Growth, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

OECD, 2016, International Migration Outlook 2016, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Productivity Commission 2020, Foreign Investment in Australia, Commission Research Paper, Canberra.

Sachs, Jeffrey. 2016. ‘Toward an International Migration Regime’, American Economic Review, vol. 106, no. 5, pp. 451-455.

Siklos, Pierre. 2021. ‘Did the Great Influenza of 1918-1920 Trigger A Reversal of the First Era of Globalization?’, CAMA Working Paper 95/2021. CAMA, Canberra.

Triggs, Adam. 2020. ‘Less foreign investment makes Australia less secure’, Inside Story, 9 June

Tuhin, Razib and Jan A. Swanepoel. 2017. ‘Export behaviour and business performance: Evidence from Australian microdata’, Department of Industry, Innovation and Science, Canberra.


Be the first to comment

Please check your e-mail for a link to activate your account.

Stay in touch

Subscribe to our monthly newsletter

Search



Cnr Gungahlin Pl and Efkarpidis Street, Gungahlin ACT 2912 | 02 6247 4396 | [email protected] | Authorised by A. Leigh MP, Australian Labor Party (ACT Branch), Canberra.